At the time of writing this paper, the constitutionality of
the 2010 health care reform package is being considered by the Supreme Court. It
is an opportune time to pause and reflect on the issues involved.
Many Democrats feel obligated to defend the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (PPACA, aka “Obamacare”) in all its particulars. This sense of obligation arises from Democratic voters’ deeply held conviction that a more ideal health care reform package would have no chance of succeeding in Congress. Even though the provisions of PPACA will produce a health care system that is demonstrably worse than the health care systems of every other Western industrialized nation, many Democrats have convinced themselves to become enthusiastic supporters of it.
On what basis may PPACA be considered deficient? Before answering this question, consider the “Iron
Triangle” of health care, described by an eminent professor of medicine named
William Kissick. The three points of this triangle correspond to the most
highly prized and interdependent aspects of health care: affordability,
quality, and access. The goal of affordability conflicts with the goals of
quality and access, because quality and access are expensive. Therefore, access
to health care and quality of health care both depend on the effectiveness of
cost-controls and the ingenuity of medical professionals in finding less
expensive ways of delivering high quality care.
Logically, then, if PPACA does not guarantee cost-effective
health care, quality and access will suffer as a result. If the cost that
consumers are required to pay in order to receive health care – the unpopular
“individual mandate” – is too high, consumers will have less money to spend.
Consumers who have little money to spend, but are not sufficiently poor to
qualify for government subsidies, will discover that they have less money on
hand to buy food or heat their homes. They will delay necessary health care
rather than take time out of work. They may wonder why they are paying high
monthly premiums and are still asked for co-pays at the doctor’s office.
Now, it is necessary to defend the position that PPACA does
not do enough to address cost. President Obama’s assertion that the act will
“bend the cost curve” is based on optimistic projections.[1] If one examines
the particulars of PPACA, the emphasis is not on controlling costs. Instead,
the emphasis is on increasing access to care. It achieves this by expanding Medicaid eligibility, allowing children
to remain on their parents’ health plans until age 26, ending exclusions for
pre-existing conditions and other provisions.
A medical device which costs $100,000 in the U.S. may only
cost $10,000 in China or India. The device is in no way inferior because of its
reduced cost. The price differential is the result of Asian nations’ culture of frugality.[2] Because
frugality is highly prized, the Asian people support their governments in
insisting on low prices. Medical device manufacturers find ways to cut costs,
maintain quality, and still earn a profit.
At this Houston hospital, harpists perform for newborns. Source. |
In contrast, Americans are inclined to be enamored by luxury.
Oscar Wilde’s quote applies: Americans, it may be said, “know the price of
everything and the value of nothing.” Costly items are assumed to be of
higher quality. As a practical consequence of this love of luxury, Americans are
not predisposed to insist on low prices, particularly not when it comes to healthcare. A courageous healthcare
reformer will show sufficient faith in the American people to believe, first,
that Americans can be educated about the hidden, unnecessary costs of healthcare
and secondly, that properly informed Americans will make wise decisions. The healthcare
reformer who values expediency will not take the chance of relying on the
wisdom of the American people.
In Houston, the average waiting time in an Emergency Department is over 4 hours. Source |
Observers believe that the focus on access was the result of
a strategic decision made by the Obama administration. The goal of expanding
access to care is less controversial than the goal of reducing costs.[3] Cost
control means a relentless effort to achieve the best possible value for the
dollar. It means increased government involvement in physicians’ decisions
about which treatments to select. It may also mean the use of waiting lists to
deter consumers from seeking treatment for non-urgent medical conditions. Cost
control means end of life counseling. So, in taking the more politically
expedient path of focusing on access, the Obama administration has handed the
American people an individual mandate that is more expensive than it needed to
be.
After all of the provisions of PPACA take effect, for-profit
health insurance companies will continue to operate very much the way they
operate now. Insurance companies may try to negotiate lower prices with
hospitals, but as it happens, insurance companies have little leverage over
hospitals in the wake of a string of mergers and partnerships that have given
hospitals monopolistic control over regions of the country. The CEO’s of companies
like Wellpoint will continue to earn
over ten million dollars per year. The health insurance lobby will continue to
pour money into political campaigns. This will invite corruption. A politician
may decide that increasing the amount of money he or she receives as campaign
contributions from the insurance lobby is a more important consideration than
ensuring that ordinary Americans receive the best value on each health care
dollar they spend.
Having said that, it is important to consider the extent to
which private insurers are guilty of profiteering. Private insurers regard
healthcare payments as a “loss” and the term “medical loss ratio” refers to the
amount of money they spend on healthcare. PPACA mandates that 80 to 85% of the
health care dollar will be used to pay medical expenses. To put this in
perspective, in 1993, private insurers spent an average of 95% of consumer
premiums on reimbursing medical expenses.[4]
The question of how that remaining 15 or 20% is spent is
germane to understanding what sort of value Americans are receiving for their
health care dollar. Within this percentage are profit and administrative costs.
It includes the cost of advertising, hiring insurance brokers to sell their
product, lobbying, paying the salaries of “government relations” specialists,
and supporting the costs of multiple private bureaucracies. The taxpayer should
chafe at the idea that his or her health care dollar subsidizes the lobbying
activity of the insurance activity, since the results of lobbying are often to
the detriment of the taxpayer. Using the administrative costs of other Western
nations as a basis for comparison, the amount of excess administration in the
private insurance industry is about 24% of total revenue.[5]
Given the fact that they are inefficient at controlling
administrative costs, it is curious that private insurance companies are being
contracted by the federal government to administer programs such as Medicaid and Medicare Advantage. Under these agreements, private insurers will contribute
nothing toward the payment of medical expenses; their task will consist of
disbursing taxpayer money to reimburse healthcare providers. In part because of
these lucrative federal contracts, private insurers have enjoyed increasing
revenues and profits since PPACA was passed in 2010.[6]
Obviously, voters can still take the position, “if it
weren’t for compromises with private corporations, PPACA could not have become
law.” This view is regrettable. Choosing to appease private corporations does
not serve the public interest. It merely allows these corporations a greater
degree of control in setting the cost of health care. Vague promises have been
made, to the effect that completion among health insurers will in time lead to
reduced costs. The skeptical voter will recall that the insurance industry is
exempt from anti-trust regulations, and recognize the discouraging parallels
that may be drawn to banking deregulation.
On the larger question of whether the United States ought to
be actively involved in healthcare delivery, it is worth noting that John Locke
sometimes included “health” alongside “life, liberty, and property” as the most
important natural rights of a free people. Locke provides a touchstone when
seeking to understand the Founders’ philosophy of government. One of the
Founders was also a physician. He was a man named Benjamin Rush, and he warned
us, “Unless we put medical freedom into the Constitution the time will come
when medicine will organize itself into an undercover dictatorship … [allowing
this to happen would be] un-American and despotic.”
Recommended Reading:
On Swiss Healthcare
[1]Dougherty. The Certitudes and
Uncertainties of Health Care Reform. Annals
of Internal Medicine.
[2]
http://www.economist.com/node/17961922
[3] Marmor et al. The Obama Administration's Options for Health Care Cost Control: Hope Versus Reality. Annals of Internal Medicine.
[4]
Potter. Deadly Spin.
[5]
http://www.pnhp.org/news/2011/november/us-health-care-spending-where-is-the-waste
[6]
media.bloomberg.com/bb/avfile/r5leWxypfaX4
No comments:
Post a Comment